Tuesday, September 24, 2013

Environmental Externalities



Environmental externalities are a particular form of externalities that economic
analysis should take into account. They should be identified and
quantified where possible and included in the economic analysis as project
costs (as might be the case for a decreased fish catch or increased illness) or
benefits (as might be the case with the reduction in pollution of coastal
areas). After assigning a monetary value to the costs and benefits, the analyst
should treat them as any other cost and benefit and enter them into the
cash flow tables.

Project Boundaries and Time Horizon

Analysts must make two major decisions when assessing environmental
impacts. First, they must decide how far to look for environmental impacts,
that is, they must determine the boundary of the economic analysis.
By assessing the internal benefits and costs of a project, the boundaries
of the analysis become clear. If the benefits accrue to the project
entity or if the costs are borne by the project entity, they enter into the
analysis. When we attempt to assess the externalities of a project to determine
its impact on society, the boundaries become blurred. Identifying
externalities implies expanding the conceptual and physical boundaries
of the analysis. A mill that generates wastewater will adversely affect
downstream uses of water for drinking, irrigation, and fishing. The analyst
can easily identify, and maybe even measure, these impacts. Other
impacts on the environment, such as the effects of emissions from a power
plant on creation of acid rain, may be more distant or more difficult to identify. How far to expand the analysis is a matter of judgment and depends
on each individual project.

The second decision concerns the time horizon. Like the project’s physical
boundaries, its time horizon also becomes blurred when we go from
financial to economic analysis. A project’s environmental impact may not
last as long as the project, or it may outlive it. If the environmental impact
lasts less time than the expected economic life of the project, the effects can
be included in the standard economic analysis. If the analyst expects the
effects to last beyond the lifetime of the project, the time horizon must be
extended. This can be done in two ways, either by extending the cash flow
analysis a number of years, or by adding the capitalized value of that part
of the environmental impact that extends beyond the project’s life to the
last year of the project. The latter technique treats the environmental impact
much as one would treat a project’s capital good whose life extends

beyond the project’s lifetime by giving it a salvage value.

Valuing Environmental Externalities



Sometimes an entity uses resources for a project without paying for them.
For example, a factory may emit soot into the air, dirtying surrounding
buildings and thereby increasing their maintenance costs. The higher
maintenance costs are a direct result of the factory’s use of a resource, air,
that from the factory’s viewpoint is free, but from society’s viewpoint
has a cost. Likewise, a new irrigation project may lead to reduced fish
catch or the spread of a disease. Sometimes a project benefits certain
groups in a way such that the project entity cannot extract a monetary
payment for them.

If a forest lowers the level of carbon dioxide in the world, the forest
owners cannot charge for the benefit. Or a sewage and water supply
project may not only improve water quality and yield direct health benefits,
but may also produce benefits from decreased pollution of coastal
areas, in turn increasing recreational use and property values. These
side effects of projects, known as externalities, are real costs and benefits
that should be included in the economic analysis as project costs or
as project benefits.

Externalities are easier to conceptualize than to measure. They occur in
production and consumption and in almost every walk of life. Involuntarily
inhaling another person’s smoke is an example of an externality. The
smoker’s pleasure produces displeasure in another person. To assess the
total pleasure derived from smoking, it would be necessary to reduce the
smoker’s pleasure by the displeasure of the person who involuntarily inhales
the smoke. Although it is easy to understand how smoking may produce
an externality, it is not as easy to assign a value to the smoker’s pleasure
or to the inhaler’s displeasure.

Externalities are easy to depict. Consider the production of a good, say,
electricity. Suppose that in producing electricity the plant emits soot that increases the maintenance costs of adjacent buildings. The utility company’s
costs would not reflect the costs to the neighbors of cleaning up the adjacent
buildings—unless the law requires it. Yet, the costs to society include
not only those that appear on the article of the utility company, but also the
additional maintenance costs of the adjacent buildings. MPC
is the marginal cost of producing electricity as reflected in the books of the
utility company, and MSC is the marginal cost of producing electricity and
cleaning up the buildings. MSC is the marginal social cost of producing
electricity. This cost would be higher than the private cost, which is the
cost to the utility company.

For any given level of output, q*, the area under the MSC curve gives the
total social cost of producing that level of output, while the area under the
MPC curve gives the perceived private cost. The difference between the areas
under the two curves gives the difference between the private and the social
cost. The financial costs of the project will not include the costs of the
externality, and, hence, an evaluation of the project based on MPC will
understate the social costs of the project and overstate its net benefits. In
principle, all we need to do to account for the externality is to work with
social rather than private costs. In practice, the shape of the MSC curve and
hence its relationship to the MPC curve is unknown, making measurement
difficult. Also, tracing and measuring all external effects is not always feasible. appear significant, to measure them. When externalities cannot be quantified,
they should be discussed in qualitative terms.

In some cases it is helpful to internalize externalities by considering a
package of closely related activities as one project, that is, to draw the project
boundary to include them. In the case of the soot-emitting factory, the externality
could be internalized by treating the factory and the neighboring buildings
as if they belonged to the project entity. In such a case, the additional
maintenance costs become part of the maintenance costs of the project entity
and are internalized. If the factory pays for the additional maintenance costs,
or if the factory is forced to install a stack that does not emit soot, the externality
also becomes internalized. In these cases, the formerly external cost
becomes an internal cost reflected in the accounts of the factory.
Nevertheless, analysts should always attempt to identify them and, if they
Quantity per

Valuation of Nontradable Goods and Services



Domestic distortions drive a wedge between economic and financial prices
of nontradable goods. Consequently, it is necessary to adjust financial
prices to reflect economic opportunity costs. The calculation of shadow
prices for nontradables, however, can be extremely time-consuming, and
project analysts must determine whether the refinement is worth the additional
effort. For example, domestic sales taxes are a common distortion;
the prices consumers pay for the good (demand price) will differ
from the price suppliers receive (supply price) by the amount of the tax.
As discussed in the technical appendix, the economic opportunity cost of
this good would depend on the elasticities of supply of and demand for
the good. Because gathering information about elasticities can be timeconsuming,
it is advisable to proceed cautiously. If the NPV of a project is
not sensitive to variations in the economic price of the input, estimating
its economic price with great accuracy is not worth the cost and an educated
guess will suffice.

Material Inputs

The first step in valuing nontradable material inputs is assessing whether
there are serious distortions in the market for the good or service. The
second step is to estimate upper and lower bounds for the economic price of the good. The final step is to decide whether to estimate the economic
opportunity cost of the good in question with a great degree of accuracy,
or simply use an educated guess.

Suppose that a project uses quarry stones that are subject to a 15
percent excise tax and that each quarry stone costs one U.S. dollar. The
project unit, therefore, pays US$1.15 for each stone, producers receive
US$1.00, and the government receives US$0.15. As shown in the technical
appendix, the economic opportunity cost of quarry stones will lie
between US$1.00 and US$1.15. As a first approximation, analysts can
estimate the project’s NPV using the two extreme values. If the project’s
NPV does not change materially as a function of the economic price of
quarry stones, it would not be worthwhile conducting time-consuming
studies to calculate the elasticities of supply and demand. A rough, educated
guess will suffice.

If, however, the project’s NPV changes from positive to negative, depending
on whether the economic price is US$1.15 or US$1.00, then it behooves
the analyst to estimate the elasticities as thoroughly as the budget
allows. These considerations are applicable to all nontradable material inputs,
and the technical appendix provides further guidance on estimating
the shadow prices of such goods.

Land

Land is a prime example of a nontradable good. In this respect its valuation
is, in principle, no different from that of any other nontradable good.
Land differs from other tradable goods, however, in that its supply is completely
inelastic: any land diverted to the project is necessarily taken away
from some other use, even if that use is speculation. Therefore, the valuation
of land for project use may have to rely on indirect methods, rather
than on straightforward use of market prices, adjusted for distortions.

If an active land market exists, land purchased specifically for project use
may be costed as a capital value using the price paid adjusted for distortions.
This is so if the analyst thinks that the market is sufficiently representative of
alternative use values for the land. If a capital value is used in costing the
land in the project accounts, then a residual value should be included at the
end of the project life. If the annual rental or lease charge is used in costing
the land, then no residual value should be shown for the land at the end of
the project life. If a lessor rents the land, then the rental value adjusted for
distortions should be considered in the project analysis.


Tradable and Nontradable Goods




Typically, a project’s inputs include material inputs, public utilities, labor,
land, and services. Some of these goods and services are tradable,
some are nontradable, and others are potentially tradable. These distinctions
are important, because the valuation of each type of good is different.
Traded goods include those that are either imported or exported by
the country. Tradable goods include all traded goods and goods that the
country could import or export under conditions of free trade, but does
not because of trade barriers such as import duties. Material inputs, however,
are normally tradable goods.

Nontradable goods are those that by their nature either cannot be traded
or are uneconomical to trade internationally. Real estate, hotel accommodations,
haircuts, and other services are typically nontradable. Nontradable
goods also include goods for which the costs of production and transportation
are so high as to preclude trade, even under conditions of free trade.
In principle, a good falls into this category if its CIF cost or landed price is
greater than the local cost. This condition precludes importation, and at
the same time, its local cost being greater than the FOB price, precludes
exportation. In some cases electric energy and transportation might be
nontradable. Land, however, is always a nontradable good.

To determine whether a good is tradable or nontradable, the first
step is to ascertain whether the good trades internationally. If no international
trade exists, then it is safe to assume that the good is
nontradable. If international trade takes place, but not in the country
where the project is to take place, the second step is to estimate the
relevant CIF and FOB prices, then compare them to the domestic price.
If the CIF price—net of import duties and subsidies—of the good is
higher than its domestic price, then the good is clearly not importable.

If its FOB price—net of export duties and subsidies—is lower than the
domestic price, then the good is clearly not exportable. Of course, the
exchange rate is crucial in this calculation. A nontradable may become
an export if the real exchange rate falls. If, by contrast, imports do not
come into the country, because, for example, import duties render the
import price higher than the domestic price, international trade does
not take place because of distortions. The good, however, is potentially
a traded good. Likewise, if duties make exports uncompetitive, the good
is potentially a traded good. All such potentially traded, but nontraded
goods, should be treated as nontradable goods.

Valuation of Tradable Goods

For various reasons, domestic market prices typically do not reflect the opportunity
costs to the country. In many countries, import duties, for example,
increase the price of domestic goods above the level that would prevail
under conditions of free trade. If the domestic price of inputs is far
higher than under conditions of free trade, a project that uses the protected
input may have a low, financial, expected NPV. Likewise, if a project produces
a good that enjoys protection, the project’s financial NPV may be
higher than under conditions of free trade. To approximate the opportunity
costs to the country, the valuation of tradable inputs and outputs in economic
analysis relies on border, rather than on domestic, market prices. The
technical annex provides a theoretical justification for using border prices
as the prices that reflect the opportunity costs to the country.

Border prices are either CIF or FOB prices suitably adjusted for internal
transport and other costs, but net of taxes and subsidies. If the country is a
net exporter of the good in question, the appropriate border price is the
FOB price of exports—also known as the export parity price. If the country
is a net importer, the appropriate border price is the CIF price of imports

plus internal transport costs—or the import parity price.

Market Prices versus Economic Costs



We now return to the main theme of this site: getting the prices right.
Once analysts have identified and measured the costs and benefits of the
project, they must price them. Financial analysts use the market price of
the goods and services paid or received by the project entity. As noted earlier,
financial analyses are conducted in the currency of the country at the
domestic price level. This means that financial costs and benefits are valued
at the prices that the project entity is expected to pay for them. Usually
these are prices set by the market, although in some cases the government
may control them. Neither market nor government-controlled prices necessarily
reflect economic costs to society.

The economic values of both inputs and outputs may differ from their
financial values because of market distortions created by either the government
or the private sector. Tariffs, export taxes and subsidies, excise
and sales taxes, production subsidies, and quantitative restrictions are
common distortions created by governments. Monopolies are a market
phenomenon that can be created by either private or public sector actions.
Some market distortions are created by the nature of the good or
service. The values to society of common public services, such as clean
water, transportation, road services, and electricity, are often significantly
greater than the financial prices people pay for them. A project that sells
electricity below its economic cost implicitly subsidizes the users of the
service. Similarly, a project that employs labor at a wage rate that is higher
than its economic cost implicitly subsidizes labor. The differences between
financial and economic prices are rents that accrue to some group in the
society and convey important information about the distribution of costs
and benefits.

Valuation of Inputs and Outputs

In economies where distortions are few, market prices provide a reasonably
good approximation of the opportunity costs of inputs and outputs.
In economies characterized by price distortions, however, market prices are a poor reflection of those costs. The financial assessment of the project
usually differs markedly from the economic assessment. An economic
analysis should assess the project’s contribution to the society’s welfare.
This evaluation requires that the analyst compensate for price distortions
by using shadow prices that reflect more closely the opportunity costs
and benefits of the project, instead of market prices. In principle, if we
adjust all prices to reflect opportunity costs, these calculations would be
extremely time-consuming and expensive. In practice, analysts undertake
few adjustments and concern themselves primarily with adjustments

of the prices of tradable goods, the exchange rate, and the wage rate.

Monday, September 23, 2013

Numeraire and Price Level



One of the earliest decisions that an analyst confronts is the choice of currency
and price level in which to conduct the analysis. In principle, analysts
can evaluate a project in any currency and at any price level. In practice,
they usually evaluate projects in the domestic currency of the country
implementing the project at prevailing market prices adjusted for distortions,
that is, at the domestic price level. These are not the only possible
choices. The two most frequently used alternatives are domestic currency
at the border price level and foreign currency at the border price level.

When analysts use domestic currency at the border price level, they calculate
the prices of all imports by taking the corresponding cost in the imports’
country of origin, adding insurance and freight (CIF) in foreign currency,
and converting it into domestic currency at the prevailing market or official exchange rate, whichever exchange rate the project entity uses to buy
foreign currency. Analysts must then adjust CIF prices for internal transport
costs. The prices of exports are calculated by taking their free on board (FOB)
prices in foreign currency, converting them into domestic currency at the
prevailing market or official exchange rate, and adjusting them for transport
costs within the country. A market exchange rate is used in this context to
mean the price at which the project entity actually gets its foreign exchange.


The prices of nontraded goods, such as services, are converted to their
border price equivalent by means of conversion factors. If the analysis is
done in foreign currency at the border price level, the prices of imports and
exports remain in foreign currency. The prices of such things as cleaning
services, however, are first converted to their border price equivalent by
means of a conversion factor, and then to their foreign currency equivalent
by means of the prevailing market or official exchange rate.

If the analysis is carried out in domestic currency at the domestic price
level, the analyst calculates the prices of imports and exports at their respective
border prices, but converts them to their domestic currency equivalent
using a shadow exchange rate that reflects the opportunity cost of foreign
exchange to the country. The analyst takes the prices of nontraded
goods and services, such as cleaning services, at their prevailing market
prices adjusted for distortions.

The price of the service (and in general of all nontraded goods whose
market prices reflect the true economic costs) would be converted as follows.
If we use domestic prices at the domestic price level, the price of the
service would be taken as given. If we use domestic currency at the border
price level, we would need to calculate the border price of the service by
using a conversion factor. In this case, the appropriate conversion factor
would be the ratio of the official to the shadow exchange rate, 0.88. If the
numeraire is foreign currency at the border price level, the border price in
domestic currency would have to be further converted to dollars using the
market exchange rate.

The choice of currency and price level is largely a matter of convenience
and will have no impact on relative prices or on the decision to
accept or reject a project. for example, the price of the imported
good relative to the price of cleaning services is 2.5:1 in all cases. As
long as relative prices are unaffected, if the NPV of a project is positive in
one case, it will be positive in all cases. Moreover, the NPV measured in
domestic currency at the domestic price level will differ from the NPV
measured in domestic currency at the border price level by the ratio of the
market exchange rate to the shadow exchange rate, that is. Therefore, one can quickly convert the NPV from one numeraire to another. The internal rate of return (IRR) remains the same, regardless of numeraire.

In most countries, the domestic price level is the price level used to
keep national accounts, the price level used by the government to reckon
its taxes and expenditures, and also the price level used by business. One
usually conducts financial analysis in domestic currency at prevailing market
prices. To integrate financial, fiscal, and economic analyses; to assess
risk and sustainability; and to identify gainers and losers, the analyst must
express the financial and economic analyses in the same unit of account.
When the financial analysis is performed in one unit of account and the
economic analysis in another, the differences between the financial and the
economic values have no meaning. Because we generally conduct financial
and fiscal analyses in domestic prices at the domestic price level, it is most convenient to carry out the economic analysis in the same unit of
account. If we use the border price level for the economic analysis, the
fiscal impact of the project would need to be calculated twice, first at the
border price level and then at the domestic price level. Moreover, for the
evaluation of projects with nontradable benefits, for example, projects in
education, health, and transportation, it is much easier to evaluate the benefits in domestic currency at the domestic price level than in some other
numeraire.


Getting the Flows Right: Identifying Costsand Benefits



Identifying costs and benefits is the first and most important step in economic
analysis. Often project costs and benefits are difficult to identify and
measure, especially if the project generates side effects that are not reflected
in the financial analysis, such as air or water pollution. Identifying the costs
and benefits of a project is one of the most important steps in economic
analysis. A second important step is to quantify them. The final step is to
value them in monetary terms.

The projected financial revenues and costs are often a good starting
point for identifying economic benefits and costs, but two types of adjustments
are necessary. First, we need to include or exclude some costs and
benefits. Second, we need to revalue inputs and outputs at their economic
opportunity costs. Financial analysis looks at the project from the perspective
of the implementing agency. It identifies the project’s net money flows
to the implementing entity and assesses the entity’s ability to meet its financial
obligations and to finance future investments. Economic analysis,
by contrast, looks at a project from the perspective of the entire country, or
society, and measures the effects of the project on the economy as a whole.
These different points of view require that analysts take different items
into consideration when looking at the costs of a project, use different valuations
for the items considered, and in some cases, even use different rates
to discount the streams of costs and benefits.

Financial analysis assesses items that entail monetary outlays. Economic
analysis assesses the opportunity costs for the country. Just because the
project entity does not pay for the use of a resource, does not mean that the
resource is a free good. If a project diverts resources from other activities that produce goods or services, the value of what is given up represents an
opportunity cost of the project to society. Many projects involve economic
costs that do not necessarily involve a corresponding money flow from the
project’s financial account. For example, an adverse environmental effect
not reflected in the project accounts may represent major economic costs.
Likewise, a money payment made by the project entity—say the payment
of a tax—is a financial but not an economic cost. It does not involve the use
of resources, only a transfer from the project entity to the government. Finally,
some inputs—say the services of volunteer workers—may be donated,
entailing no money flows from the project entity. Analysts must also
consider such inputs in estimating the economic cost of projects.

Another important difference between financial and economic analysis
concerns the prices the project entity uses to value the inputs and outputs.
Financial analysis is based on the actual prices that the project entity pays
for inputs and receives for outputs. The prices used for economic analysis
are based on the opportunity costs to the country. The economic values of
both inputs and outputs differ from their financial values because of market
distortions created either by the government or by the private sector.
Tariffs, export taxes, and subsidies; excise and sales taxes; production subsidies;
and quantitative restrictions are common distortions created by governments.
Monopolies are a market phenomenon that can either be created
by government or the private sector. Some market distortions are
created by the public nature of the good or service. The values to society of
common public services, such as clean water, transportation, road services,
and electricity, are often significantly greater than the financial prices people
are required to pay for them. Such factors create divergence between the
financial and the economic prices of a project.

Economic and financial costs are always closely intertwined, but they
rarely coincide. The divergence between financial and economic prices
and flows shows the extent to which someone in society, other than the
project entity, enjoys a benefit or pays a cost of the project. Sometimes
such payments are in the form of explicit taxes and subsidies, as in a
sales tax; sometimes they are implicit, as in price controls. The magnitudes
and incidence of transfers are important pieces of information that
shed light on the project’s fiscal impact, on the distribution of its costs
and benefits, and, hence, on its likely opponents and supporters. By identifying
the groups benefiting from the project and the groups paying for
its costs, the analyst can extract valuable information about incentives
for these groups to implement the project as designed, or to support it
or oppose it.

A thorough evaluation should summarize all the relevant information
about the project. To look at the project from society’s and the implementing
agency’s viewpoint, to identify gainers and losers, and ultimately to
decide whether the project can be implemented and sustained, it is necessary
to integrate the financial, fiscal, and economic analyses and identify

the sources of the differences.

Separable Components



Sometimes a project consists of several interrelated subprojects or components.
When the components are independent, each component must be
treated as if it were a separate project. The analyst then must determine
whether each component increases or decreases the project’s total NPV.
Any component with negative NPV should be dropped, even if the total
NPV of all the components is positive. Each separable component must
justify itself as a marginal part of the overall project.

Suppose a project provides three benefits: hydroelectric power, irrigation
water, and recreational facilities. If the benefits and costs of each component
are independent of each other, then the components are separable and can
be treated as independent projects. In this case, the decision to include each
component in the final design will depend solely on whether the NPV of the component is positive. But if the water is needed early in the year for irrigation
and only later in the year to meet peak demand for electricity, and if the
tourist season occurs at the end of the year, the three uses might conflict. For
example, maximizing the use for electricity generation might result in an
empty reservoir when the tourist season begins. If maximizing the NPV of
the whole package entails reducing the efficiency of one component, then
dropping one or more components might result in an overall package with a
higher NPV. In this case, the components are not mutually exclusive and,
hence, not separable.

Appraising such a project requires three steps:

• The analyst must appraise each component independently.
• The analyst must appraise each possible combination of components.
• The analyst must appraise the entire project, including all the components, as a package.

Thus, the analyst must appraise the hydroelectric component separately,
considering the most appropriate technology for generating electricity and
disregarding its uses for irrigation or recreation. Similarly, the analyst must
appraise the irrigation component as an irrigation project, choosing the
most appropriate design for irrigation and disregarding its potential use
for electricity generation or recreation. Finally, the analyst must appraise
the recreation component independently using the same general approach.

The second step would involve appraising three combinations, hydroirrigation,
hydro-recreation, and irrigation-recreation. In each case, the most
appropriate technology for the combination would be used, and the NPV
of each combination would be assessed.

The final step would be to evaluate the design that combines all three
components. This design would also be predicated on a technology that
maximizes the NPV from the combined facilities. We would thus have seven
alternatives: hydroelectricity, irrigation, recreation, hydro-irrigation, hydrorecreation,
irrigation-recreation, and hydro-irrigation-recreation. The preferred
alternative would be the one that yields the highest NPV without
exceeding the budget.

If the components are separable, then the NPV of the combinations is
equal to the sum of the NPVs of each separable component. If the components
are not separable, then the NPV of the combinations is not equal to
the sum of the NPVs of each component. In this table the NPVs of the
combinations are greater than the NPVs of the sums of the individual components.
This, however, does not need to be the case. If the components
are not separable, then choosing the combination with the highest NPV
entails assessing the NPV of each combination and choosing the one with

the highest NPV.