Domestic
distortions drive a wedge between economic and financial prices
of
nontradable goods. Consequently, it is necessary to adjust financial
prices to
reflect economic opportunity costs. The calculation of shadow
prices for
nontradables, however, can be extremely time-consuming, and
project
analysts must determine whether the refinement is worth the additional
effort. For
example, domestic sales taxes are a common distortion;
the prices
consumers pay for the good (demand price) will differ
from the
price suppliers receive (supply price) by the amount of the tax.
As discussed
in the technical appendix, the economic opportunity cost of
this good
would depend on the elasticities of supply of and demand for
the good.
Because gathering information about elasticities can be timeconsuming,
it is
advisable to proceed cautiously. If the NPV of a project is
not
sensitive to variations in the economic price of the input, estimating
its economic
price with great accuracy is not worth the cost and an educated
guess
will suffice.
Material
Inputs
The first
step in valuing nontradable material inputs is assessing whether
there are
serious distortions in the market for the good or service. The
second step
is to estimate upper and lower bounds for the economic price of the good. The
final step is to decide whether to estimate the economic
opportunity
cost of the good in question with a great degree of accuracy,
or simply
use an educated guess.
Suppose that
a project uses quarry stones that are subject to a 15
percent
excise tax and that each quarry stone costs one U.S. dollar. The
project
unit, therefore, pays US$1.15 for each stone, producers receive
US$1.00, and
the government receives US$0.15. As shown in the technical
appendix,
the economic opportunity cost of quarry stones will lie
between
US$1.00 and US$1.15. As a first approximation, analysts can
estimate the
project’s NPV using the two extreme values. If the project’s
NPV does not
change materially as a function of the economic price of
quarry
stones, it would not be worthwhile conducting time-consuming
studies to
calculate the elasticities of supply and demand. A rough, educated
guess will
suffice.
If, however,
the project’s NPV changes from positive to negative, depending
on whether
the economic price is US$1.15 or US$1.00, then it behooves
the analyst
to estimate the elasticities as thoroughly as the budget
allows.
These considerations are applicable to all nontradable material inputs,
and the
technical appendix provides further guidance on estimating
the
shadow prices of such goods.
Land
Land is a
prime example of a nontradable good. In this respect its valuation
is, in
principle, no different from that of any other nontradable good.
Land differs
from other tradable goods, however, in that its supply is completely
inelastic:
any land diverted to the project is necessarily taken away
from some
other use, even if that use is speculation. Therefore, the valuation
of land for
project use may have to rely on indirect methods, rather
than on
straightforward use of market prices, adjusted for distortions.
If an active
land market exists, land purchased specifically for project use
may be
costed as a capital value using the price paid adjusted for distortions.
This is so
if the analyst thinks that the market is sufficiently representative of
alternative
use values for the land. If a capital value is used in costing the
land in the
project accounts, then a residual value should be included at the
end of the
project life. If the annual rental or lease charge is used in costing
the land,
then no residual value should be shown for the land at the end of
the project
life. If a lessor rents the land, then the rental value adjusted for
distortions
should be considered in the project analysis.
0 comments:
Post a Comment