Tuesday, September 24, 2013

Valuing Environmental Externalities



Sometimes an entity uses resources for a project without paying for them.
For example, a factory may emit soot into the air, dirtying surrounding
buildings and thereby increasing their maintenance costs. The higher
maintenance costs are a direct result of the factory’s use of a resource, air,
that from the factory’s viewpoint is free, but from society’s viewpoint
has a cost. Likewise, a new irrigation project may lead to reduced fish
catch or the spread of a disease. Sometimes a project benefits certain
groups in a way such that the project entity cannot extract a monetary
payment for them.

If a forest lowers the level of carbon dioxide in the world, the forest
owners cannot charge for the benefit. Or a sewage and water supply
project may not only improve water quality and yield direct health benefits,
but may also produce benefits from decreased pollution of coastal
areas, in turn increasing recreational use and property values. These
side effects of projects, known as externalities, are real costs and benefits
that should be included in the economic analysis as project costs or
as project benefits.

Externalities are easier to conceptualize than to measure. They occur in
production and consumption and in almost every walk of life. Involuntarily
inhaling another person’s smoke is an example of an externality. The
smoker’s pleasure produces displeasure in another person. To assess the
total pleasure derived from smoking, it would be necessary to reduce the
smoker’s pleasure by the displeasure of the person who involuntarily inhales
the smoke. Although it is easy to understand how smoking may produce
an externality, it is not as easy to assign a value to the smoker’s pleasure
or to the inhaler’s displeasure.

Externalities are easy to depict. Consider the production of a good, say,
electricity. Suppose that in producing electricity the plant emits soot that increases the maintenance costs of adjacent buildings. The utility company’s
costs would not reflect the costs to the neighbors of cleaning up the adjacent
buildings—unless the law requires it. Yet, the costs to society include
not only those that appear on the article of the utility company, but also the
additional maintenance costs of the adjacent buildings. MPC
is the marginal cost of producing electricity as reflected in the books of the
utility company, and MSC is the marginal cost of producing electricity and
cleaning up the buildings. MSC is the marginal social cost of producing
electricity. This cost would be higher than the private cost, which is the
cost to the utility company.

For any given level of output, q*, the area under the MSC curve gives the
total social cost of producing that level of output, while the area under the
MPC curve gives the perceived private cost. The difference between the areas
under the two curves gives the difference between the private and the social
cost. The financial costs of the project will not include the costs of the
externality, and, hence, an evaluation of the project based on MPC will
understate the social costs of the project and overstate its net benefits. In
principle, all we need to do to account for the externality is to work with
social rather than private costs. In practice, the shape of the MSC curve and
hence its relationship to the MPC curve is unknown, making measurement
difficult. Also, tracing and measuring all external effects is not always feasible. appear significant, to measure them. When externalities cannot be quantified,
they should be discussed in qualitative terms.

In some cases it is helpful to internalize externalities by considering a
package of closely related activities as one project, that is, to draw the project
boundary to include them. In the case of the soot-emitting factory, the externality
could be internalized by treating the factory and the neighboring buildings
as if they belonged to the project entity. In such a case, the additional
maintenance costs become part of the maintenance costs of the project entity
and are internalized. If the factory pays for the additional maintenance costs,
or if the factory is forced to install a stack that does not emit soot, the externality
also becomes internalized. In these cases, the formerly external cost
becomes an internal cost reflected in the accounts of the factory.
Nevertheless, analysts should always attempt to identify them and, if they
Quantity per

0 comments:

Post a Comment