The conceptual approach for calculating economic opportunity costs assumes that governments purchase inputs for use in their own projects in fairly well-functioning, but distorted markets. As a result of their purchases, governments add to the existing market demand and consequently bid up the price of goods and services. The approach further assumes that the additional government demand is satisfied either through (a) reduction of consumption of the good on the part of existing consumers, (b) increased production of the good on the part of existing producers, or (c) a combination of both.
The
value to society of the goods or services diverted to the project is the sum of
the values consumers place on the forgone consumption, plus the cost of
increasing production. This conceptual framework is based on the following
three basic postulates:
• Competitive demand price measures the benefit of each
marginal unit to the demander.
• Competitive supply price, or marginal cost, measures
the opportunity cost of each marginal unit from the suppliers’ standpoint.
• The benefits and costs to a society as a whole are
equal to the difference between benefits and costs.
These three postulates imply that in a distortion-free,
well-functioning market, the market clearing price measures the benefit of each
marginal unit to the demander and also measures the cost of each marginal unit
for the supplier. In such a market, the social opportunity cost of goods and services
equals their market clearing prices, which in turn implies that society’s cost
of transferring one unit of a good to a government project is given by the
market price of the good.
Distortions and externalities destroy this appealing
symmetry. A distortion such as a sales tax introduces a wedge between the
prices that demanders and suppliers face. In such cases the marginal social
benefit, as measured by the price paid by demanders, differs from the price
that suppliers face by the amount of the tax. As a result, we can no longer
rely on the market price as an indicator of the cost to society of transferring
one unit of a good to a government project, because there are now two prices: the
price that demanders pay and the price that suppliers receive.
When the government demands goods and services in
distorted markets, the question that arises is: Which price reflects the
economic cost to society? If a reduction of consumption by existing demanders
satisfies the additional government demand, then according to the first
postulate, the cost to society will be the value consumers place on the forgone
consumption.
The value of one additional unit will be given by the
price that demanders pay. If an increase in production solely satisfies the
additional government demand, then according to the second postulate, the cost
to society will be the cost of increasing production and the value of one
additional unit will be given by the price that producers receive.
If a diversion of existing demand and an increase in
supply satisfies the additional demand, the third postulate implies that the
value to society of the goods and services diverted to the project is the sum
of the values consumers place on the forgone consumption plus the cost of increasing
production. The relevant price will be a weighted average of the supply and
demand prices.
This basic approach can be used to estimate the economic
opportunity cost of every resource, including foreign exchange, labor, and
capital. The basic principle is the same. We view the government as an additional
demander of a resource. This additional demand bids up the price of the resource,
and consequently the quantity required by nongovernment demanders falls and the
quantity supplied rises. The additional government demand is partly satisfied
by the displacement of existing consumption and partly by the increase in production. The value to
society of the resources used equals the sum of the values consumers place on
their forgone consumption and the cost to suppliers of the additional
production.
In distorted markets, the difference between the
financial and economic price is indicative of a rent that someone in the
economy receives. If taxes are the source of the distortion, the difference
between the economic and financial prices indicates the amount of taxes that
the government forgoes. If the distortion stems from monopoly power, then the
difference between the financial and the economic price signals a change in
monopoly rents. For example, suppose the government was to purchase goods in a
market subject to a sales tax, and the supply of those goods was completely
inelastic. The additional government demand would have to be satisfied solely from
reduced consumption. Total consumption and production would remain the same,
but government revenues would fall.
Similar analysis applies in every instance where the
financial and economic prices and flows differ. If the source of the distortion
is monopoly power, a government purchase that stimulates supply would increase monopoly
rents. If the source of distortion is quantitative restrictions (QRs), then
those enjoying the benefits of QRs would gain. Whenever economic and market
prices differ, some group other than the project entity, either pays a cost of
the project or enjoys some of its benefits.
Identifying the sources of divergence between economic
and financial prices and flows helps assess gainers and losers. Because taxes
are a common source of divergence, full use of the information available helps
assess the fiscal impact of projects. Putting together the financial
information, the fiscal implications, and the distribution of costs and
benefits among the various actors in the economy creates a richer and more
informative analysis.
0 comments:
Post a Comment